Draft:Rakesh Sarin
![]() | Review waiting, please be patient.
This may take 2–3 weeks or more, since drafts are reviewed in no specific order. There are 372 pending submissions waiting for review.
Where to get help
How to improve a draft
You can also browse Wikipedia:Featured articles and Wikipedia:Good articles to find examples of Wikipedia's best writing on topics similar to your proposed article. Improving your odds of a speedy review To improve your odds of a faster review, tag your draft with relevant WikiProject tags using the button below. This will let reviewers know a new draft has been submitted in their area of interest. For instance, if you wrote about a female astronomer, you would want to add the Biography, Astronomy, and Women scientists tags. Editor resources
Reviewer tools
|
Submission declined on 26 June 2025 by CharlieMehta (talk). This submission's references do not show that the subject qualifies for a Wikipedia article—that is, they do not show significant coverage (not just passing mentions) about the subject in published, reliable, secondary sources that are independent of the subject (see the guidelines on the notability of people). Before any resubmission, additional references meeting these criteria should be added (see technical help and learn about mistakes to avoid when addressing this issue). If no additional references exist, the subject is not suitable for Wikipedia.
Where to get help
How to improve a draft
You can also browse Wikipedia:Featured articles and Wikipedia:Good articles to find examples of Wikipedia's best writing on topics similar to your proposed article. Improving your odds of a speedy review To improve your odds of a faster review, tag your draft with relevant WikiProject tags using the button below. This will let reviewers know a new draft has been submitted in their area of interest. For instance, if you wrote about a female astronomer, you would want to add the Biography, Astronomy, and Women scientists tags. Editor resources
This draft has been resubmitted and is currently awaiting re-review. | ![]() |
Comment: In accordance with the Wikimedia Foundation's Terms of Use, I disclose that I have been paid by my employer for my contributions to this article. HRShami (talk) 05:32, 26 June 2025 (UTC)
Rakesh Kumar Sarin | |
---|---|
Occupation(s) | Decision analyst, author, and academic |
Academic background | |
Education | BE in Mechanical Engineering MBA in Management MS in Management PhD in Management |
Alma mater | M.R. Engineering College Indian Institute of Management University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA) |
Academic work | |
Institutions | University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA) |
Rakesh Kumar Sarin is a decision analyst, author, and academic. He is a Distinguished Professor and holds the Paine Chair in Management at the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA).
Sarin’s research has investigated theories concerning laws of happiness and decision-making. He is an elected fellow of the Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences.
Education and early career
[edit]Sarin completed his BE in Mechanical Engineering at M.R. Engineering College in 1969 and his MBA in Management from the Indian Institute of Management in 1971. He earned his MS and PhD in Management from the University of California in 1973 and 1975, respectively.[1]
Career
[edit]Sarin began his career as an assistant professor at the Indian Institute of Management from 1975 to 1976. Subsequently, he assumed the position of decision analyst at Woodward Clyde Consultants, a role he held until 1977. At Purdue University, he worked as an assistant professor between 1977 and 1979, and at Duke University, he held the position of IBM research professor from 1987 to 1990. He joined the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA) as an assistant professor in 1979, was appointed associate professor in 1981, and became a professor in 1985. Since 1990, he has also been the Paine Chair in Management at UCLA.[1][2] He was the editor-in-chief of Decision Analysis from 2013 to 2018.[3]
Research
[edit]During his early years of research work, Sarin established that fairness judgments were greatly influenced by equity in the distribution of risks and benefits, with people preferring balanced trade-offs between compensatory benefits and mortality risks.[4] Some of his early work was on prescriptive models of decisions with multiple objectives. Together with Dyer, he developed a measurable multi-attribute value function theory and presented conditions for multiplicative and additive forms for it.[5] Along with Wakker, he documented that dynamic choice could support unexpected utility models, with sequential consistency guaranteeing coherence, particularly for multiple priors, while rank-dependent and betweenness models continued to be more limited in application.[6] Together, they also stipulated a structure for modeling uncertainty beyond conventional expected utility assumptions by incorporating cumulative dominance, strengthening the basis of probabilistic sophistication.[7] Additionally, while undermining the validity of Fox and Tversky's arguments in non-comparative settings, he demonstrated the persistence of ambiguity aversion and showed that comparative ignorance widened valuation gaps.[8]
With Abramson and others, he showed that competitive decision making was greatly influenced by information access, particularly decision aids, which increased price competition and reduced profits.[9] He also determined that when payments were made available without cognitive load, normatively sound choices predominated; however, retrospective evaluations of payment sequences exhibited duration neglect and peak-end effects, mostly under distraction.[10] By incorporating satiation into discounted utility, he underscored that recent consumption reduced current utility, deviating from standard DU predictions, particularly for short intervals, however agreeing with them for long intervals.[11]
In a collaborative study, he concluded that in situations of uncertainty, dyads remained cautious, continually displaying risk-averse shifts and strengthening resistance to ambiguity in group decision-making, rather than having two heads reducing ambiguity resistance.[12] He also observed how variety-seeking and habitual utilization influenced the decision-making process and explained biases like projection bias in consumption behaviors by showing that satiation and habit formation impacted utility predictions.[13]
Works
[edit]Sarin authored a book titled Engineering Happiness: A New Approach for Building a Joyful Life, where he examined happiness by employing behavioral sciences.[14] Stefan Trautmann, in his review of the book, commended the author's efforts in succeeding "to show the reader the potential effects of social comparisons, losses, adaptation etc. on our life satisfaction"; however, he also criticized the book for being complicated despite it being "advertised for people 'regardless of background, profession or aspirations'".[15] The book also won the Decision Analysis publication award in 2014.[16] His other book Perspectives in Operations Management: Essays in Honor of Elwood S. Buffa compiled essays on the field of operations management.[17]
Awards and honors
[edit]- 2000 – Neidorf "Decade" Teaching Award, UCLA Anderson School of Management[18]
- 2006 – J. Clayburn Laforce Faculty Leadership Award, UCLA Anderson School of Management[18]*2009 – Frank P. Ramsey Medal, Decision Analysis Society[19]
- 2012 – Elected Fellow, Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences[20]
Bibliography
[edit]Books
[edit]- Buffa, Elwood; Sarin, Rakesh (2007). Modern Production / Operations Management, 8th Ed. Wiley. ISBN 9788126513727.
- Baucells, Manel; Sarin, Rakesh (2012). Engineering Happiness: A New Approach for Building a Joyful Life. University of California Press. ISBN 9780520268210.
- Sarin, Rakesh (2012). Perspectives in Operations Management: Essays in Honor of Elwood S. Buffa. Springer. ISBN 9781461531661.
Selected articles
[edit]- Sarin, R.; Wakker, P. P. (1998). "Dynamic Choice and Nonexpected Utility". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 17 (2): 87–119. doi:10.1023/A:1007769628257.
- Chow, C. C.; Sarin, R. K. (2001). "Comparative Ignorance and the Ellsberg Paradox". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 22 (2): 129–139. doi:10.1023/A:1011157509006.
- Chow, C. C.; Sarin, R. K. (2002). "Known, Unknown, and Unknowable Uncertainties". Theory and Decision. 52 (2): 127–138. doi:10.1023/A:1015544715608.
- Baucells, M.; Sarin, R. K. (2003). "Group Decisions with Multiple Criteria". Management Science. 49 (8): 1105–1118. doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.8.1105.16400.
- Baucells, M.; Sarin, R. K. (2010). "Predicting Utility Under Satiation and Habit Formation". Management Science. 56 (2): 286–301. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1090.1113.
References
[edit]- ^ a b "Rakesh Sarin–BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH" (PDF). University of California, Los Angeles. Retrieved May 12, 2025.
- ^ "Endowed Chairs, Presidential Chairs, Professorial Name Chairs". University of California, Los Angeles. Retrieved May 12, 2025.
- ^ "Editorial Board – Decision Analysis". INFORMS. Retrieved May 12, 2025.
- ^ Bian, Wen‐Qiang; Robin Keller, L. (January 1999). "Patterns of Fairness Judgments in North America and the People's Republic of China". Journal of Consumer Psychology. 8 (3): 301–320. doi:10.1207/s15327663jcp0803_06.
- ^ Dyer, James S.; Jia, Jianmin (2013). "Preference Theory". Encyclopedia of Operations Research and Management Science: 1156–1159. doi:10.1007/978-1-4419-1153-7_787.
- ^ Segal, Uzi (1999). "Dynamic Consistency and Non-Expected Utility". Uncertain Decisions: 39–52. doi:10.1007/978-1-4615-5083-9_2.
- ^ Grant, Simon; Özsoy, Hatice; Polak, Ben (May 2008). "Probabilistic sophistication and stochastic monotonicity in the Savage framework". Mathematical Social Sciences. 55 (3): 371–380. doi:10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2007.10.002.
- ^ Fox, Craig R.; Weber, Martin (May 2002). "Ambiguity Aversion, Comparative Ignorance, and Decision Context". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 88 (1): 476–498. doi:10.1006/obhd.2001.2990.
- ^ Hogarth, Robin M. (December 1989). "Ambiguity and competitive decision making: Some implications and tests". Annals of Operations Research. 19 (1): 29–50. doi:10.1007/BF02283513.
- ^ Galiani, Sebastian; Hajj, Nadya; McEwan, Patrick J.; Ibarrarán, Pablo; Krishnaswamy, Nandita (1 August 2019). "Voter Response to Peak and End Transfers: Evidence from a Conditional Cash Transfer Experiment". American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. 11 (3): 232–260. doi:10.1257/pol.20170448.
- ^ He, Ying; Dyer, James S.; Butler, John C. (December 2013). "On the Axiomatization of the Satiation and Habit Formation Utility Models". Operations Research. 61 (6): 1399–1410. doi:10.1287/opre.2013.1223.
- ^ le Roux, Sara; Kelsey, David (2014). "Strategic Substitutes, Complements and Ambiguity: An Experimental Study". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2521377.
- ^ Deshmane, Abhishek; Askin, Noah; Kim, Khwan (September 18, 2022). "Syncing Preferences: Dynamic Reference Formation in Digital Service Platforms". IESE Business School Working Paper. Retrieved 26 June 2025.
- ^ "Engineering Happiness: A New Approach for Building a Joyful Life". WorldCat. Retrieved May 16, 2025.
- ^ Trautmann, Stefan (2012). "Engineering Happiness – A New Approach for Building a Joyful Life, Manel Baucells, Rakesh Sarin. UC Press, Berkeley, CA (2012). xii +233 pp., $25.95 (pb), ISBN: 978-0520268210. An online mathematical appendix is available at ucpress.com". Journal of Economic Psychology. 33 (6): 1269–1270. doi:10.1016/j.joep.2012.08.009.
- ^ "Decision Analysis Publication Award". INFORMS. Retrieved May 23, 2025.
- ^ "Perspectives in Operations Management: Essays in Honor of Elwood S. Buffa". WorldCat. Retrieved May 16, 2025.
- ^ a b "Faculty Awards–UCLA Anderson School of Management". University of California, Los Angeles. Retrieved May 12, 2025.
- ^ "Frank P. Ramsey Medal". INFORMS. Retrieved May 12, 2025.
- ^ "INFORMS Fellows: Class of 2012". INFORMS. Retrieved May 12, 2025.